Category Archives: Uncategorized

A Fine Wynne Godley Article On Keynesianism From 1984

There is a fine Wynne Godley article from the year 1984 titled Confusion In Economic Theory And Policy — Is There A Way Out? in the book After Stagflation: Alternative To Economic Decline, edited by John Cornwall, 1984, in which he discusses his worldview and how Keynesianism should work. In this he talks of how Keynesianism requires international coordination of not just fiscal policy but also management of international trade.

He starts off by how Keynesianism demand management works:

The policy makers of that era and those who advised them particularly in Britain and the United States came, generally speaking, to share a view, the authorship of which was correctly attributed to Keynes, that governments could, and therefore should, accept responsibility for ensuring real growth and full employment. And those same people also believed that the success, at that time, of the industrialized economies was the consequence of the implementation of Keynesian policies.

While the idea that governments can and should accept responsibility for maintaining full employment can be attributed to Keynes, the theoretical basis of the explicit or implicit models used in practice to underpin Keynesian policy advice was pretty crude. The essential points were as follows.

  1. To obtain real growth and full employment it was necessary and sufficient to expand aggregate demand for goods and services. Governments could achieve this by expanding their own expenditure on goods and services or releasing disposable income by cutting taxation.
  2. There might be a temporary constraint on the growth of real output imposed by shortage of physical or human capital. A constraint might also be imposed if exports did not rise sufficiently to pay for imports.
  3. Subject to these constraints, fiscal policy could safely adopt full employment as a target while disregarding any imbalance in the Budget — that is, any excess of public spending measured in nominal terms over revenue receipts.
  4. Monetary policy under this system of ideas did not matter much, the quantity of money itself being a residual number thrown up by everything else that happened which could safely be ignored. It was even the case through much of the post-war period that statistics relating to what are now called ‘monetary aggregates’ (the stock of money and various other financial assets) were not regularly available, if at all.¹

NOTES

  1. In other words people thought and built econometric models which were based on an ‘IS’ mechanism without any (operative) ‘LM’ process; if these models contained a representation of the financial system, that did not make any important differences to the solutions they generated.

And later:

…  I am prepared to assert that the macroeconomic theory on which policy was based in the successful post-war period was essentially correct after all.11

I do not for a moment accept that the post-war Keynesian consensus has been in any way confuted by events.

NOTES

  1. In the appendix I have attempted to set out rigorously, if briefly, why this is so, and how the confusion in Keynesian macroeconomics can be resolved and why the most important change which I have had to make in my views about macroeconomic policy has nothing to do with the theory of inflation as such, nor about monetary aggregates, ‘crowding out’ etc. It has to do with the importance of the proper inflation accounting of all national-income accounting concepts i.e. stocks as well as flows. It is (maybe?) slowly coming to be realized that, to be meaningful as a measure of fiscal stance, a budget deficit must be corrected for cyclical movements. It has still to be understood that public deficits, if they are to be measures of the determinants of real demand and output, must also be corrected for the erosion of the money value of the stock of government debt (including ‘inside’ money) from inflation.

Then Wynne Godley talks of how Keynesianism would need international coordination:

Even if I am correct in supposing that the post-war Keynesian system of ideas was a basically correct foundation for economic policy this does not, unfortunately, mean there is a simple solution to the problem of world recession by simply reverting to old ways. Even if my views about the key role of fiscal policy were generally accepted and monetary targeting were abandoned, the world economic situation has now gone so badly wrong that it would be very difficult to put things right again. To achieve sustained growth would require that countries cooperate with one another in an altogether new way, coordinating their plans as they have never done before.

The conclusion must be that even if we could now coordinate fiscal policies to accommodate the fact that different countries are in different degrees of recession, I am quite sure that very large current-account imbalances would emerge. So we need not only to coordinate our fiscal policies, we also need to coordinate our trade policies and payments as well. Yet, under the present system of floating exchange rates, we have been deprived of the traditional means of making balance-of-payments adjustments. Paradoxically, by having floating exchange rates we have deprived ourselves of exchange rates as an instrument of economic policy.

In sum, I believe that there is no intrinsic reason why growth and full employment in the industrialized world should not be achieved by coordinated fiscal policies in combination with an appropriate configuration of exchange rates. The difficulties are first that action and cooperation along these lines are not at all what governments at present have on their agenda; second there does not at present exist a system of information and analysis which could form the basis for such a coordinated plan of action; third, even if exchange rates could be adjusted to satisfy the long-run conditions for equilibrium, the trade responses to currency adjustment are known to be very slow so there would be a long transitional period during which potential-deficit countries would have to suffer large increases in import prices (and therefore inflationary pressure) and cuts in real income.

I am, therefore, very doubtful if, even supposing that international cooperation was attempted, it could now really be successful without some form of international trade management. By trade management I do not mean protection in the sense ordinarily understood, i.e. a situation where individual countries unilaterally protect individual weak industries without international agreement and in a way unrelated to general macroeconomic management.

What I have in mind is that deficit countries adopt the kind of protection specifically catered for in the little read and, I believe, never used Article 12 of GATT which is specifically designed to make full employment possible in countries which would otherwise be subject to a general balance-of-payments constraint. The key point of such trade management would be, first, that it would be operated as a macroeconomic instrument, in harmony with fiscal policy, so as to ensure that the balance of payments would not be any more favourable than would otherwise be the case; in other words such protection would be used entirely to make possible higher domestic production reducing the import propensity without reducing total imports themselves below what they otherwise would be. Under such conditions the rest of the world does not suffer (its exports being, by assumption, fully maintained) and the recovery of output can be much more rapid and less inflationary.

Is The US Public Debt Sustainable?

The US public debt is rising $1 trillion every 100 days, headlines say. Is the US public debt sustainable?

Well, the US net international investment position is on an unsustainable path and that reflects on the US public debt. The solution is not fiscal contraction but using policy to address the US balance of payments.

According to the Federal Reserve release Z.1, the US net international investment position was −$19.37 trillion at the end of 2023. (Table B.1, line 24), while the Gross Domestic Product for 2023 was $27.36 trillion. (Table F.2, line 1).

Since government deficit is connected to the current account balance by an identity,

NL = DEF + CAB

where NL is the private sector net lending, DEF is the government deficit, CAB is the current account balance, it suggests a connection between the government deficit and current account balance not just as a static identity but behaviourally and there is a connection between the public debt and the net international investment position. In behavioural stock-flow consistent models, this can be seen more clearly.

The US has had high current account deficits and that has put the US economy on an unsustainable path.

And in general, there is no market mechanism to resolve imbalances. Lots of political discourse in the US has been around trade/tariffs etc. Industrial policy has also appeared. Note that many people define industrial policy as government picking winners, but that is misleading/a deceit. The aim of industrial policy is to improve competitiveness of a country and that has to do with exports and imports.

A lot of people complaining about the path of the US public debt seem to suggest that the way to solve it is via fiscal contraction. But that causes a deflation of the US economy and increases unemployment.

But sadly, the other side denies that there is any problem with sustainability/trade etc. So we have crazy politics. An important problem is the lack of understanding how economic forces operate. Or that people’s self-interests stand in the way of understanding.

Note that “r < g” is not a condition for sustainability.

The resolution of the problem lies in the US asking the rest of the world to increase growth by more fiscal expansion (which would increase US exports and reduce US imports relative to GDP), use protectionist measures and industrial policy and then work toward a system of planned/regulated trade where international trade is generally balanced.

R.I.P., Anthony Thirlwall

Anthony Thirlwall has passed away. His work is highly important in Post-Keynesian economics. Here is what one of his ex-students Mohammed Nureldin Hussain said about the Thirlwall Law in The Implications Of Thirlwall’s Law For Africa’s Development Challenges in the book Growth And Economic Development: Essays In Honour Of A.P. Thirlwall:

The Professor started to work out the mathematics of his manuscript. The good old blackboard notwithstanding, the identities and equations of the model were animated, left-handedly, in a manner that competes easily with Bill Gates’ PowerPoint facilities. The model contained three basic equations representing the growth of imports, the growth of exports, and a dynamic expression of the overall balance of payments equilibrium. He substituted the first two equations into the third and the model was solved to yield an elaborate expression of the growth rate of real gross domestic product (GDP). When the terms of trade were assumed to be constant the elaborate equation collapsed into an expression containing three symbols: y = x/π. ‘The rate of growth (y) of any developed country in the long run is equal to the growth rate of the volume of its exports (x) divided by its income elasticity of demand for imports (π)’, he explained.

Our eyes were fixed on the blackboard, attempting to digest the meaning and internalize the implications of this tri-legged animal. That job was not easy. For the animal distilled volumes of legendary work in economic development, encapsulating all of them in a small-sized anti-underdevelopment pill. The teaching of Engel’s law, which implies that the demand for primary goods increases less than proportionally to increases in global income; the Harrod foreign trade multiplier which put forward the idea that the pace of industrial growth could be explained by the principle of the foreign trade multiplier;3 the Marshall– Lerner condition which implies that a currency devaluation would not be effective unless the devaluation-induced deterioration in the terms of trade is more than offset by the devaluation-induced reduction in the volume of imports and increase in volume of exports; the Hicks super-multiplier4 which implies that the growth rate of a country is fundamentally governed by the growth rate of its exports; the Prebisch–Singer hypothesis which asserts that a country’s international trade that depends on primary goods may inhibit rather than promote economic growth; the Verdoorn–Kaldorian notion that faster growth of output causes a faster growth of productivity, implying the existence of substantial economies of scale;5 Kaldor’s paradox which observed that countries that experienced the greatest decline in their price competitiveness in the post-war period experienced paradoxically an increase in their market share and not a decrease; the literature on export-led growth which asserts that export growth creates a virtuous circle through the link between output growth and productivity growth – all of these doctrines were somehow put into play and epitomized within this small-sized capsule. Not only that but the capsule was sealed by the novel and powerful ingredient of the balance-of-payments constraint: ‘in the long run, no country can grow faster than that rate consistent with balance of payments equilibrium on current account unless it can finance ever-growing deficits which, in general, it cannot’.

The time for class discussion came and all the debate seemed to linger around one basic query: if growth could be explained by a rule which contained two variables only, what was the relevance of the many other socio-economic variables that could also influence the growth process? What about the role of policies and economic management? What about the role of capital, labour and technical progress? The answers of the Professor were convincing to some students, but confusing to many others. In an attempt to relieve our baffled faces he concluded the discussion by saying, in a pleasant fusion of smile and speech: ‘Simple laws make good economics’. And as he was leaving the classroom, his smile turned gradually into a laugh that engulfed his remark: ‘if this rule came to be known as Thirlwall’s Law, I will retire’. Less than one year after the publication of the manuscript in 1979 the rule was crowned as ‘Thirlwall’s Law’. But, retire? He did not. I suppose genuine philosophers like this man will never retire even if they wanted to.

NOTES

  1. See Kaldor (1978).
  2. See McCombie (1985).
  3. See Kaldor (1975).

REFERENCES

Kaldor, N. (1975), ‘Economic Growth and the Verdoorn Law – A Comment on Mr. Rowthorn’s Article’, Economic Journal, 85(340), December, 891–6.

Kaldor, N. (1978), ‘The Effects of Devaluation on Trade in Manufactures’, in N. Kaldor, Further Essays on Applied Economics, London: Duckworth.

McCombie, J.S.L. (1985), ‘Economic Growth, the Harrod Foreign Trade Multiplier and the Hicks Super-multiplier’, Applied Economics, 17(1), February, 55–72.

Appreciated/referrred by Anthony Thilwall himself in his article Balance Of Payments Constrained Growth Models: History And Overview from the year 2012.

Trump Proposes A Ring Around The Collar

In a recent interview with Larry Kudlow, Donald J. Trump has proposed a 10% tariff on all goods and services produced by nonresident economic units which he calls “a ring around the collar”.

Trump has a chance to be reelected the President of the United States and it’s noteworthy not just because of that but because there is hardly anyone proposing the same. I think that the US balance of payments and hence its financial position is in an unsustainable path and it has to take such measures.

It is important to realise that Trump was using protectionist measures in his Presidency, he faced ridicule from supposed experts. But soon when Joe Biden became the President, Biden not only continued Trump’s policy but also did more to try to improve the US’s net international investment position.

But instead of acknowledging this, the expert class obviously has its narrative. It’s partly to do with the fact that they don’t want to acknowledge that they were wrong and the rest with the fact that they want to return to the old world order of free trade once the US presumably improves its economic/financial position.

Paul Krugman has a Twitter thread and an article in The New York Times on this. It’s a tribe defense, plus a plan to keep this as it is after a small change, with the assumption that it will succeed.

The Euro Area Crisis As A Balance-Of-Payments Crisis

In a recent blog post Revisiting The Euro Crisis, J. W. Mason argues that the current account imbalances in balance of payments isn’t a/the cause of the Euro Area crisis.

This is completely wrong!

Current account deficits have an effect on the government budget balance and a higher current account deficit would lead to a higher budget deficit than otherwise. This is not just a matter of accounting but true behaviourally. The large current account deficits ultimately caused a large public debt and investors in government debt became nervous and there was a crisis in the government bond markets of the Euro Area. Since lot of government debt is held by foreigners, as it is difficult for residents to hold all that debt (when there’s large net international indebtedness), the sale and the movement of funds abroad after the sale also resulted in a banking crisis, as banks went heavily overdraft at their NCBs and didn’t have sufficient collateral.

The crisis in banking and government bond markets caused more crisis in private debt markets and fiscal retrenchment, fall in GDP and that leading to more crisis!

As simple as that!

One of Mason’s arguments is that since lending by foreigners needn’t arise out of prior saving, the result liabilities owed to foreigners isn’t really debt. But how does it follow that one thing implies the other? If foreigners transfer a large amount of funds to accounts in their home countries, there would be a banking crisis as banks would find it difficult to post collateral to their NCB (National Central Bank). The government would have to rescue banks adding to public debt and making investors nervous.

Greek banks endogenously creating money doesn’t mean that a purchase of a German product by Greek residents doesn’t reduce Greek’s net asset position or increase its net indebtedness to Germany.

Mason says:

 Many people with a Keynesian background talk about endogenous money, but fail to apply it consistently

Perhaps he is the one failing?

Take a simpler example: loans make deposits. But it’s also true that deposits are funding banks. The fact that banks created funds doesn’t imply that the created deposit isn’t a liability or debt.

Mason also discusses how the TARGET2 system works with the ECB/NCBs. The NCBs have  unlimited and uncollateralised overdrafts with each other and unlike the arrangements prior the formation of the Euro Area, there isn’t an equivalent worry about central banks running out of reserves. But unlimited overdrafts for the NCBs does not imply unlimited overdrafts for the whole country! It’s just that the crisis is seen elsewhere, like in banking and the government bonds markets.

Mason also takes issue with phrases such as “capital flight”. But investors can sell assets and move funds to another country and that can put pressure on banks. How is the phrase not helpful in describing what is going on?

The problem with the Euro Area is that with exchange rates fixed irrevocably and with governments prevented from making overdrafts at their NCBs, governments cannot devalue their currency or take independent fiscal action than allowed by markets. Fixed or floating, the problem is there, and the Euro Area setup makes it worse. Doesn’t remove the problem altogether!

You can see from the data from Eurostat that Euro Area countries with the worst net international investment position were the ones seeing the worst crisis. The net international investment position is accumulated current account balance plus revaluations/holding gains/”capital gains”.

Of course, the solution of the crisis isn’t wage deflation (sometimes referred to as internal devaluation), but the formation of a central government. With the central government, there are fiscal transfers with some Euro Area countries receiving more from the government than what they send in taxes. This would improve the current account balance of those countries, keeping imbalances in check. A central government would both be able to take independent action and keep imbalances in check.

Michael A. Landesmann On Nicholas Kaldor On The Centrifugal Forces At Work In The Euro Area

I have noted many times since the Euro Area crisis started how Nicholas Kaldor foresaw it much earlier than anyone else. The year: 1971 ‼

I came across this article Nicholas Kaldor And Kazimierz Łaski On The Pitfalls Of The European Integration Process by Michael A. Landesmann, published in Dec 2019, which is really good. I like the phrase centrifugal forces in the abstract, as the Euro Area is designed to cause countries in it to fly apart.

An interesting snippet:

In sum, Kaldor’s analysis of the pitfalls of the Common Market comprises three components:

  • the almost unavoidable processes leading to ‘structural external imbalances’;
  • the detrimental impact of the Common Agricultural Policy (CAP), for a country like the UK …
  • the fact that external imbalances would result in a ‘deflationary bias’ in the deficit countries … This tendency would be strengthened in a fixed exchange-rate regime and, even more so, in a monetary union that would not be complemented by a fiscal union.

Kaldor’s analysis points to an issue that is of central importance in the set-up of the EC (and continues to be of great relevance in the EU): the likelihood of what he calls the emergence of ‘structural (external) imbalances’. He refers in this respect to G. Myrdal’s ‘circular and cumulative causation’ processes … Which are the cumulative processes that Kaldor alludes to when predicting that integrated groups of countries will experience ‘structural external imbalances’?

Economists On US Manufacturing And Trade

Recently, Paul Krugman wrote two articles in The New York Times on recent surge in US manufacturing: Making Manufacturing Great Again (June 6, 2023) and Making Manufacturing Greater Again (April 20, 2023).

Post-Keynesians stress the importance of manufacturing and exports/international trade. Before the economic and financial crisis which started in 2007, Wynne Godley was worried about all this and proposed to improve exports and take measures such as imposing non-selective protectionism, as he thought—rightly—that a crisis would happen and fiscal policy should be used and would be used but that alone will not be sufficient. In other words, the market mechanism won’t do the trick.

The reason manufacturing is important is because of the potential for expansion of exports.

Economists however have been denying all this. Especially with the rise of Donald Trump when attempts to improve the US balance of payments/international investment position were looked upon as clownish. But now the establishment has accepted that it needs to be addressed. But they don’t want to accept that they were behind. At the same time, Joe Biden has gone beyond measures that Trump has taken.

However, there are many economists who still live with old dogmas. For example, see Adam Posen’s article America’s Zero-Sum Economics Doesn’t Add Up for Foreign Policy.

So we have two types of mainstream economists: a) those who grudgingly accept that they were wrong and b) who are still wedded to dogmas.

There’s of course a limit to this, so the solution to the problems lie in disbanding the system of free trade and move toward a system of balance-of-payments targets.

Marc Lavoie On The Shortcomings Of The Profit Inflation Theory

Marc Lavoie has an article, Some Controversies In The Causes Of The Post-Pandemic Inflation at the  blog, Monetary Policy Institute Blog.

From the article:

In the post-Keynesian tradition, firms usually operate in an area where marginal costs, or unit direct costs, are constant. Taking into account overhead labour costs and other fixed costs, unit costs are thus decreasing up to full capacity. This means that with a given markup rate over unit direct costs (or with a given markup rate over normal unit costs), profits will be rising for two reasons … First, as firms produce and sell more units, their unit cost drops, and hence their realized profit per unit gets bigger, and secondly since they sell more units, they will make more profits.

A lot of heterodox authors have endorsed the profit inflation theory and there are even research reports from the Wall Street claiming the same! But according to Marc Lavoie’s argument they just explain it in only some industries like the oil industry.

Nicholas Kaldor On Monetary Policy And Stability Of Financial Instituitions

Via Eric Tymoigne’s blog post, I came across this quote from Nicholas Kaldor in 1982 (page 13) on stability/solvency of financial institutions, especially relevant in recent times:

Given the fact that most, if not all, types of financial institutions have short-term liabilities, the interest payment on which varies in strict relation to the Bank Rate, whilst their assets consist in a large part of bonds or mortgages, the income from which is (or may be) fixed, there must clearly be limits to the freedom of the central bank to use the interest weapon if the solvency and viability of financial institutions is to be preserved. This is only one aspect of a wider problem of the Bank of England in its policies of debt-management (regarded by the Committee as the ‘fundamental domestic task of the central bank’), which must be so conducted as to provide various types of debt in the amounts and proportions in which the public desires to hold them subject to the Bank’s powers to influence the public’s preferences by altering the relative yield on various types of debt.

That’s from his book The Scourge Of Monetarism.

It’s a fantastic book and clearly shows how Kaldor is a monetary economist of rank 1.

A favourite quote from the book is (next page) and which I quote often in this blog:

… As it is, a highly developed banking system already provides such facilities on an ample scale, since it is prepared to accommodate the public’s changing demand between different types or financial assets by altering the composition of the banks’ assets or liabilities in a reverse direction. If the non-banking public wishes to switch its holding of gilts for interest-bearing bank deposits, the banks are ready to supply such deposits at the minimum of inconvenience, and at the same time to place their surplus funds into the gilts which were previously held by the public. Similarly the banks provide easy facilities to their customers for switching balances on current accounts into interest-bearing deposit accounts, or vice versa. Hence, while the annual increment in the total holding of financial assets of the private sector (considered as a whole) is nothing more than the mirror-image of the borrowing requirement of the public sector (in a closed economy at any rate), neither the Government nor the banks can determine how much of this increment will be held in the form of cash (meaning notes and current deposits) and how much in the near-equivalents to cash (such as interest-bearing demand deposits) or in various forms of public sector debt. Thus neither the Government nor the central bank can control how much or the total financial assets the public prefers to hold in the form of ‘money’ on one particular definition or another.

Marc Lavoie On Recent Controversies On Inflation

There’s a new talk (from 22nd February) by Marc Lavoie (available on YouTube) on the recent controversies on relatively high inflation in recent times in North America.

Marc had already talked on this before.

Profits vs profits margins vs costing margins.

The above screenshot summarises Marc Lavoie’s points. The discussion appears around 16:00 in the video.

Lots of left-leaning economists have claimed the idea of profits being the source of high inflation. An example is a recent paper by Isabella Weber (and Evan Wasner) who claim that under conditions of supply constraints, firms can hike prices.